Tuesday, November 8, 2011

Investitures, Authority and the Consolidation of Royal Solidarity Evidence from Germany and Rome

Susan Reynolds’ work Kingdoms and Communities is a study of the various communal[1] ties that made medieval society a coherent whole. Indeed, in her introduction, she states that there was much greater interregional coherence in communal processes during the medieval period.[2] The corollary here is that, in spite of the criticism by various scholars, we can, in fact, speak of a coherent Medieval Europe.[3] One such process is that division or conflicts fosters bonds, not only at the local level, but also at the level of the realm. This response investigates this claim with the evidence provided by the investiture controversy.[4] Clearly, two polities are at work, Rome and the Holy Roman Empire, with a third group of polities, perhaps the most important, Italian cities.

In chapter 6 of her book, Susan Reynolds argues that the way towns grew was not primarily an economic necessity. This revolutionary argument brings to historical discourses, what was present in archaeology, that is, that there is no dual purpose (one military, the other economic) to towns. Rather, large settled, and most importantly fortified areas, became the foci for many communal activities, ranging from assemblies of magnates, to some primarily local trade.[5] The large markets, though, appear as a consequence of the size of these settlements, and were not a cause of urbanization.[6] Then, the main reason for urbanization is political. So too the bonds that tied together a community were, at least initially, political.[7]

Then, it becomes necessary to consider the creation of the towns in the context of political dynamics. Indeed, the towns were still part of a system, and were often dependent on a patron. Lübeck is one example, where the emperor is plays a major role. Indeed, the emperor guarantees not only the existence of privileges, but also that the privileges are to be enforced. In addition, the emperor is also able to grant privileges that extend beyond the city itself, that is “that the people of Lübeck should enjoy the right and conditions that the people of Cologne, Tiel […] and their members enjoy” (Lübeck is made an Imperial City, Class handout, p.50). The example of Laon provides another example: the bishop’s approval was necessary, even from a simply legal standpoint, for the privileges to be granted. Guillaume of Nogent states that after the oaths of association were broken, the people “such rage, such amazement seized the burghers that all the craftsmen abandoned their jobs and the stalls of the tanners and cobblers were closed […] ” (The Formation of the Commune at Laon, Handout, p.39). Two conclusions arise. First, the role of the lord or patron is still crucial for the existence of the commune, and second, crisis creates ties within these urban communities. Indeed, what in common would the tanners, cobblers, innkeepers and chapman have in common that they all decided to strike? Then cohesion is made at the local level in the context of crisis.

There is little doubt that the investiture contest polarized the constituencies involved, both at the local level and the level of the realm.[8] One letter of Gregory to Otto, bishop of Constance, from 1074, provides an interesting example of the way the contest divided loyalties, and by extension communities. Indeed, Gregory writes to Otto in order that Otto would enforce Gregory’s legislation on the priesthood. Otto’s actions show that, at least initially, he must have aligned himself with the emperor: “A report has come to us [royal we, refers to Gregory] with regard to Your Fraternity, which I have heard with grief and regret […]. Wherefore we command you to present yourself before us […] to give answer […] for this disobedience and contempt of the Apostolic See” (Tierney, p.48-49). It appears, then, that there were different loyalties at play that were more important that loyalty to the ecclesia catholica. It is worth noting also that, in the letter, it is not just the bishop who is in canonical wrong, but his community of priests. Indeed, Otto “presides over the numerous clergy and the widespread population,” chose not to punish “those who had taken concubines persisted in their crime, while those who had not yet done so had no fear of your prohibitions” (Tierney, p.50). In other words, the conflict does not involve just the bishop, but his whole community.

Finally, the Concordat of Worms (Sept 1122) can be seen as a compromise, much in the same light as the Magna Carta: it is a piece of collective activity, where two communities were unable to break the other, were asserting their rights. Focusing on the rights of the Holy Roman Emperor, it becomes apparent that the Emperor had sought to create with some cohesion a group of people bound to him in loyalty. Thus, the bishop-elect receives the regalia from the king, even if the latter promises “canonical elections and free consecration.” Thus, two communities are appearing in this document forms: the Holy Roman Empire, with ties to an emperor, and local communities, which retain the ability to elect their bishops. Frederick II, for all his troubles, retained sufficient authority and loyalty to raise armies.[9] Thus, the Imperial office did not lose loyalties in this contest (and in fact created new ones).

Thus, the investiture contest provides evidence that Reynolds’ view that contest divides in a way to strengthen communal bonds is a particularly shrewd and correct observation.



[1] Intended here in the wider sense of the term, as the adjective of community.

[2] Susan Reynolds, Kingdoms and Communities in Western Europe, 2nd Ed (New York: Oxford University Press, 1997), p.7-8.

[3] For the criticism, see Dominique Barthélémy, The Knight, the Serf and the Historian (Ithaca: Cornell University Press): his main criticism of Duby is the enlargement of the study of the Macônais to the whole of Europe. While on the surface this appears coherent, after Reynold’s work, the historian should reconsider his position, and admit that there are interregional processes, though we must still account for the fact that these took place at different times, and, as a consequence, causality is dependent on context. Still the processes take the same shape.

[4] The primary documents are taken from Brian Tierney, The Crisis of Church and State 1050-1300 (Toronto: Toronto University Press, 1988), chapter 2. When noted otherwise, they come from class handouts.

[5] It is also worth noting that the large fairs of Champagne were not placed in a strategic location for long –distance trade, even if they eventually became hubs of international trade in the late-twelfth, early-thirteenth century.

[6] Susan Reynolds, Kingdoms, pp.155-158. The implicit reasoning is based on Braudel’s capitalism surveys, which consider that the city requires markets to supply it. That is, because town-folks often specialized their activities away from basic sustenance, there was a necessity for outsourcing basic needs. This duty fell on peasants. As towns grow, Braudel argues, so does the supply zone. Fernand Braudel,Les Structures du Quotidien (Paris: Armand Colin, 1979), see esp. chapter 1. Susan Reynolds uses this argument, Susan Reynolds, Kingdoms, esp. pp. 158-165.

[7] Susan Reynolds, Kingdoms, especially chapter 3, pp. 184-198. The main argument is that guilds, even if they become economic entities, initially began as common ‘interest groups’,’ which would take over some administrative duties (at times acting as electoral structures), or religious festivals (which cannot be dissociated from political life).

[8] I will focus primarily on the evidence from the Empire.

[9] Susan Reynolds, Kingdoms, p.295.

Mercantilism, Consolidation and Gifts: The Importance of the Fairs of Champagne.

I will not be concerned, in this response, with the important authority that the Fairs of Champagne conferred on the Counts. It suffices mainly to consider how the crisis with the Piacenza merchants. The fairs provided enough of revenue for merchants that the potentate of Piacenza engaged in a series of diplomatic exchanges with the count of Champagne, so as to avoid exclusion from the fairs (Evergates, Document 24).

Of greater interest to me is the importance of the wealth that was generated by the fairs, and the fact that they appear to have played an integral role in the development of Champagne as a rather unified county. In other words, the wealth that was derived from the fairs, being tremendous, was spread to various other institutions, including monasteries and vassals, which allowed for the counts to consolidate their county politically.

I have recorded, from document 51 in the source handout, the amount of wealth that the counts of Troyes would have been able to gather from two fairs, the first at Troyes and the second at Provins (the other two fairs, according Evergates (Evergates, p.28), were Bar-sur-Aube and Lagny), amounted to about 4000 pounds, for the years 1276 to 1278 (source packet document 51). It would be wrong to assume that they were this large in 1164 or 1174, in the time of Henry I.

We can, however, think that the amount of revenue from rents in the market (that is without rents from room OR from weighing taxes) to under ten percent of what the merchants would bring. Indeed, the value of the fair in Provins is given at 1000 pounds in 1275, for the fair taking place between June 24th and September 8th (source packet, doc 51). The first letter of Thibault, stating that merchants from Siena, Florence, Pistoia, Lucca and Pisa had been despoiled of 12,000 worth of good while they were on their way to the fair of Provins. The fact that the letter is dated to October would tend to show that the fair these despoiled merchants were travelling to had to have been the St Ayoul Fair, which takes place from September 14 to November 1. It is unlikely that we would be dealing with the May Fair, given the sum in question and the pace of responses. Indeed, letter two from February 1243, is a response to another letter. That means that in four months three letters had been exchanged, which gives us an average time of five weeks per letter. Then the merchants of Siena and the other cities would have left to go to the St Ayoul fair. Since their goods were estimated at 12,000 pounds and the revenue of the fair is estimated at 1,000 pounds, a figure of ten percent revenue is a large estimate for the ratio between the value of the goods exchanged and the value of the fair to the count.

It is not, however, a ratio that would out of place given the merchandises exchanged. The Italian merchants exchanged luxury goods like spices and silk (Evergates, p.28). The merchants from other cities citied by the third letter of Thibault (Toulouse, Marseille, Metz, Lyon) and local merchants would probably be selling cheaper goods, and thus their aggregate wealth would not amount to the wealth of the Italian merchants. I will proceed under the assumption that this ratio would have been somewhat constant, even if it fluctuated annually.

These fairs, then would have provided the count with an impressive margin to give out gifts to monasteries and to purchase lands from castellans. It is no wonder, then, that Thibault, in his testament of 1257, is able to bequeath such largesse on the monasteries. For instance, he gives 200 pounds to Clairveaux, or 1,000 pounds to the poor commoners of Champagne (document 53), given that he had some assurance that he would receive a large revenue stream from his fairs. His wealth is not limited to the fairs, of course, and would have also come from rents in fiefs.

There is some evidence that these fair money could have been used to purchase fiefs. In the purchase of the lands of Roger, lord of Rozoy-en-Thiérarche, it is stated that he receives 500 pounds, in addition to a rent of 60 pounds to be taken from the fairs at St Ayoul (document 7). Given the context, and though Roger becomes their vassal, he receives a great amount money for his fief. Given that, according to Evergates, 100 pounds invested in property and five pounds annual rent is sufficient for a simple lifestyle (document 28), the 60 pounds in rent (in addition to other rents Robert might have received from other fiefs) would have been plenty. That Robert chooses for this rent to come from the St Ayoul fair is not surprising, it would have been a sure stream of money.

Thus, the importance of the fairs for Champagne can hardly be overstated. Indeed, they provided the counts of Champagne with an insured revenue stream, which could be brokered against property, or even given as gifts. Thus, the wealth of the merchants of Italy reached many places, including the lower castellans of Champagne.